New Zealand’s kiwisaver scheme
has proven to be a political success. Created in 2007 in response to an
impending slump the number of people in work relative to people in retirement,
funds have grown by leaps and bounds. The plan has now become a politically and
fiscally indispensable part of New Zealand’s future collective retirement
savings. As of March 2013, membership had reached 2 million, or just under half
of New Zealand’s total population of 4.4 million [1].
Since 2008, members have saved over $14 billion, or 40% of the $35 billion in
New Zealand super funds [2].
There’s a number of changes one
could make to kiwisaver to make it a better fit for the way people relate to
their money and retirement savings in practice. Much of basic economics assumes
people are ‘homo economicus’, an entirely rational human capable of perfect
market action, but knowledge about human psychology – our biases, systematic
mistakes, and evolutionary ‘flaws’ - can
help us design a savings system better suited for homo sapiens. There are a number of features in kiwisaver that
approach an intuitive, homo sapiens
model, but several improvements could be made. First, there may be more
cost-effective ways to incentivise people to join the plan - and commit an adequate level of savings to it - than putting $1000 towards
their savings at the start. Second, gradual increases in contribution rates,
especially timed with increases in income, could help people to reach a higher,
more realistic retirement savings level. Third, there does exist an argument
for a publicly-run kiwisaver scheme in competition with the current private
ones, although the argument rests more on economics than cognitive psychology.
The graph shows the total
payments made for each financial year since the year ending 2008. Payments have
continued to climb with membership since the scheme started.
In their book Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health,
Wealth, and Happiness, Thaler and Sunstein argue that human cognitive
biases prevent us from behaving in ways conducive to our own best interests,
and that often – particularly in an economic system based around homo economicus, or purely rational
beings, operating in a free market – we have outcomes that are less than
optimal for both individuals and for society. It is well recognized in
cognitive psychology that we have a tendency toward making cognitive errors in
particular defined ways. Thaler and Sunstein’s argument is that where possible,
economies and societies should be redesigned in such a way that – without
preventing people from making their own choices – it becomes easier for people
to make good choices and easier to avoid making bad ones.
One simple example of this kind of design can be found in retirement schemes like New Zealand’s kiwisaver. The kiwisaver scheme gives employees an immediate 250% return on their investment and continued return until they retire, leading many personal finance advisers to describe joining the scheme as a “no-brainer”, despite the fact that law prevents savers from taking their money out of their kiwisaver account until they reach retirement age. If people starting a new job are, by default, outside the scheme and must opt-in to take advantage of it, they have the freedom to decide whether to invest in the scheme or not, but doing nothing will leave them out of it. On the other hand, if people starting a new job are, by default, inside the scheme, but can opt-out if they wish, people still have freedom to decide whether to belong to the scheme, but doing nothing will allow them to take full advantage of the scheme. In each case, individuals must implicitly or otherwise make a choice about belonging to the scheme; in each case, individuals have the freedom to decide whether they’d like to invest in the scheme or not; but the latter case will lead to much more money saved in kiwisaver and likely much more funds available to people when they retire.
One simple example of this kind of design can be found in retirement schemes like New Zealand’s kiwisaver. The kiwisaver scheme gives employees an immediate 250% return on their investment and continued return until they retire, leading many personal finance advisers to describe joining the scheme as a “no-brainer”, despite the fact that law prevents savers from taking their money out of their kiwisaver account until they reach retirement age. If people starting a new job are, by default, outside the scheme and must opt-in to take advantage of it, they have the freedom to decide whether to invest in the scheme or not, but doing nothing will leave them out of it. On the other hand, if people starting a new job are, by default, inside the scheme, but can opt-out if they wish, people still have freedom to decide whether to belong to the scheme, but doing nothing will allow them to take full advantage of the scheme. In each case, individuals must implicitly or otherwise make a choice about belonging to the scheme; in each case, individuals have the freedom to decide whether they’d like to invest in the scheme or not; but the latter case will lead to much more money saved in kiwisaver and likely much more funds available to people when they retire.
Thaler and Sunstein’s helpful (if
slightly contrived) mnemonic NUDGES
describes what they believe “choice architects” can do to design better choices
for people:
- iNcentives
- Understand mappings
- Defaults
- Give feedback
- Expect error
- Structure complex choices
The current structure of kiwisaver
results from the usual mix of opposing ideals and political decision-making
from New Zealand’s Labour government from its introduction to 2008 and then the
National Party government from 2008 until the present. But the question can be
asked whether the system measures up to the standards described by Thaler and
Sunstein’s “NUDGE” mnemonic.
Immediate financial incentives have in some form been
present in the scheme since its inception. Although kiwisaver savers potentially accrue a return at market rates throughout the life of their
investment, a special bonus is obtained immediately at the outset. First,
government offered an initial “kick-start” payment of $1000 when individuals
join the scheme. Second, government and employer subsidies are added at the
same time individuals contribute to their scheme. This last feature has been
tweaked a number of times since 2007; the National government reduced required
employer subsidies from a maximum of 4% to 2% in 2009, but more recently raised
those subsidies to 3%, while lowering the government subsidy. The extent to
which financial incentives such as these operate as real psychological
incentives is questionable, and there may have been better ways to incentive
participation in the scheme using more immediate awards. Thaler and Sunstein
explicitly used Kiwisaver to point out the questionable power of purely
economic incentives (relative to intelligent defaults). Despite the $1000
kickstart offered by the government for kiwisaver, after merely six months, the
automatic enrolment for people starting new jobs was the main method of
enrolment, despite the kickstart enticing people to join through active
enrolment [3].
If more immediate incentives are more powerful, perhaps a “rewards” scheme, as
is popular with credit card accounts, may be more cost-effective. Although less
government money goes into the scheme, more immediate incentives could be more
powerful and ultimately lead to more money in the scheme altogether. However,
such “bribes” have their own problems; they could undermine the extent to which
the scheme is taken seriously. The kickstart also functions as a direct
investment in each individual’s retirement fund.
People should be able to understand mappings of choice labels and descriptions into outcomes. Too often, choice presentations and labels do not easily and intuitively suggest outcome. Understanding mappings in choices with kiwisaver could be a
significant challenge for potential savers. Individuals must choose between
an array of index-tracked and actively managed funds without necessarily
understanding how funds are invested. In fund promotional brochures, past fund
performance is always indicated next to a disclaimer Past performance is no indication of future returns, leading
consumers to either rely on them anyway or wonder about the point of such
indications. Scheme providers such as the ASB Bank describe their own schemes
using labels describing points in a continuum from “Conservative” to “Growth”.
Still, only a few schemes (the Gareth Morgan Scheme is one exception) allow
investors to see exactly which stocks and bonds their money is invested in,
which might constrain the ability of more financially-literate investors to
make their own best possible choices about funds in which to invest.
The power of an intelligent default opt-in for enrolling members in
kiwisaver has been described above. A default opt-in could have opted in all
employees, with an option to opt-out if they wished, and would have seen even
more powerful results. This kind of automatic opt-in could still be applied at
present, though it does seem that the majority of working-age New Zealanders
are now in the scheme. However, Thaler and Sunstein extensively discussed
examples of setting intelligent defaults for investors’ contribution level and
the scheme into which they’re enrolled. Thaler and Benartzi’s successful “Save
More Tomorrow” private savings scheme enrolls members at an initial low rate –
say, 1% - and increases members’ rate in sync with their pay rises. In that
way, members commit to very little in the short term, making the scheme easier
to start, but in the long term, build a worthwhile savings rate and never have
to adjust to a lower income as a result. In a company where the scheme was
tried, just 25% of employees increased their contributions rate by 5% when
recommended to by an advisor, but 78% of those who declined agreed to the “Save
More Tomorrow” gradual rate increase scheme. Three years later, while the first
group were contributing an average of 9% to their savings scheme, the second
group – initially contributing just 1% - were contributing 13.6%, very close to
the 15% recommended as optimum for the whole group by advisors. Apparently the
plan has caught on, because by 2007, 39% of large employers in the USA were
reported to use some variant of automatic rate increase.
Further default setting concerns
for retirement funds include appropriate exposure to risk (high-growth,
high-risk investments for people far from retirement, to low-growth, low-risk
investments for those about to retire) and choosing a particular default fund.
Thaler and Sunstein explained that Sweden’s privatized social security model,
introduced last decade, allocated members to a carefully chosen, government run
scheme, run in the model of Sweden’s previously successful government funds, if
they failed to pick one for themselves. It turned out this scheme performed
better, than the average of schemes chosen by savers themselves. In the New
Zealand system, when a new member joins kiwisaver, if employers do not choose, rather
than allocating the member to a carefully chosen scheme, government randomly
allocates members [4] to
one of a group of several private schemes chosen by the government. Such random
allocation, while relying on private schemes, blunts market competition for
quality, an essential part of any privately-run investment offering. Care
should be taken when encouraging members to choose their own scheme, as members
don’t necessarily choose better than a well-designed default; any default
should avoid the kind of market inertia which could arise from randomly
allocating members to private schemes. Morningstar’s most recent Kiwisaver
Performance Survey report [5]
named 5 best-performing kiwisaver providers over the previous 3 years or 5;
none of these schemes were government defaults; though the report doesn’t
mention any impact which management fees might have on investor returns. One
might wonder whether private, government-appointed default scheme providers
have less incentive to provide well-performing schemes.
Feedback for kiwisaver schemes might include clear and transparent
information about returns and management fees. Savers ought to be able to
easily compare and choose competing schemes. As this article is primarily
focused on human factors related to kiwisaver, it’s beyond the scope of this
article to examine deeply the way that different schemes can vary. Successive
governments have tweaked kiwisaver disclosure rules.
Kiwisaver schemes are designed
with some kind of expectation of error, at least in terms of potential mistakes
made by clients and managers. Rules specify who is qualified to give different
kinds of kiwisaver advice – as I write, the New
Zealand Herald reports those rules have just been relaxed somewhat, though
apparently only temporarily [6].
Structuring complex choices is the other topic Thaler and Sunstein
discussed extensively with regard to government savings schemes. Investment
experts know a number of facts not well understood by many kiwisaver savers, from basic principles like “diversifying”, to appropriate exposure to risk, to
expert opinion in judging performance of investments. Currently the sheer number of schemes offered across all providers makes for very complex decisions on the part of savers. Savers need to be given an easy, clear, process to choose the scheme that is best for them, taking into account issues such as risk profile.
Inevitably, design of
government-run savings schemes will be influenced by political realities. There
are also practical constraints, such as the level of government and employer
contributions deemed wise. Other legitimate debates exist about the merits of
individualized savings schemes such as kiwisaver compared to schemes provided
for by general taxation and paid out at a specified rate, such as New Zealand’s
current Superannuation system. But within the constraints of an individual
contribution system, where the amount paid out is determined by the amount
invested and market returns, there remain a number of ways in which the system
can be improved. These include tweaks to government incentives, a graduated,
automatic, and optional rise in contribution rate with rises in income, and
close scrutiny of default plans with consideration of a publicly-run option.
[1] Dwyer,
M. (2009) The Place of Kiwisaver in New
Zealand’s Retirement Income Framework. http://www.cflri.org.nz/sites/default/files/docs/RI-Review-2013-KiwiSaver.pdf,
p6. Retrieved 18 August 2013.
[2] Douglas,
C. (2013) KiwiSaver Performance Survey
June Quarter 2013. http://www.morningstar.co.nz/s/documents/KiwiSaver-Survey-30-06-2013.pdf.
Retrieved 18 August 2013.
[3]
KiwiSaver evaluation reports: KiwiSaver Six-monthly report 1. http://www.ird.govt.nz/aboutir/reports/research/report-ks/research-ks-2007-12-31.html.
Retrieved 18 August 2013.
[4] KiwiSaver:
Choosing your KiwiSaver scheme. http://www.kiwisaver.govt.nz/new/providers/
[5] http://www.morningstar.co.nz/s/documents/KiwiSaver-Survey-30-06-2013.pdf.
Retrieved on 18 August 2013.
[6]
David Chaplin, The New Zealand Herald,
15 August 2013. “Code on the road - new rules for advisers” http://www.nzherald.co.nz/david-chaplin/news/article.cfm?a_id=616&objectid=10912346.
Retrieved on 16 August 2013.
No comments:
Post a Comment